The referendum is a decision made by the Syriza government because it
has run out of road. Syriza lacking strategic vision is entrapped in a
political cul de sac. Its politics have reached their limits. After
approximately five months of negotiating with the EU leadership the
abject result is capitulation to austerity. The recent draft deal would
have meant the acceptance of even more austerity. Accepting such a deal
would have split Syriza and alienated much of its popular support.
Rather than face this it fell back on the referendum tactic. But this
forthcoming referendum can only add to the confusion and further
demoralisation of the Greek working class. This is because the
referendum is ambiguous. It is not clear as to what it is about. It is
not clear as to whether it concerns a vote for or against the Euro and
even EU membership. The brevity of the campaign and the surrounding
financial conditions entailing bank holidays, capital controls and cash
withdrawal restrictions may not help debate. The referendum, as it
stands, is a manifestation of the political bankruptcy of Syriza.
Should the public vote yes in this forthcoming referendum it will mean
the transfer of political power back to the previous conservative Greek
forces. In that way Syriza will have, in effect, surrendered power to
these conservative forces thereby missing a golden opportunity to
actively participate in the radicalisation of the Greek and European
masses towards the seizure of popular power and the establishment of
communism. But Syriza's very nature prevented it from such an
achievement. Its function is the disarming of the Greek working class.
The Greek crisis is an acute and concrete manifestation of the limits of
capitalism. The Greek crisis can only be resolved on a European and
global basis through the popular democratic establishment of communist
society. It is not a choice between being in or outside of the Euro.
Both choices are capitalist I character entailing austerity.
Anti-austerity is only realizable through a popular based social
revolution that transcends the limits and contradictions of capitalism.
The various programmes advanced by much of the radical left are lodged
within the limits of capitalism. But it is these very limits that the Greek
financial crisis is manifesting. Leftists proposing the limits of
capitalism to solve those very limits is a contradiction.
The principal problem, then, is not the bourgeoisie. The principal
problem is the failure of the working class to recognise through its
experience the Greek situation as a manifestion of the limits of
capitalism. This is not, as such, an objective problem but a subjective
one. It is a problem of the consciousness of the Greek and European
working class --class consciousness. Capitalism in the form of the Greek
crisis is telling the working class that it, capitalism, has limits and
thereby cannot satisfy the needs of the workers. Yet the working class
resist this thereby persisting in the maintenance of the deluded image
of a capitalism that can overcome its own limits.
Showing posts with label The Capitalist Crisis. Show all posts
Showing posts with label The Capitalist Crisis. Show all posts
Friday, October 30, 2015
No Anti-Austerity Campaign Can Be Successful Under Capitalism
The Greek working class have no option but the promotion of European
communist insurrection to abolish the EU and the capitalism that it
supports. The Greek working class cannot achieve communist on a national
basis. A revolution confined to Greece would be strangled at the hands
of European and US capitalism. Greek society is too weak to successfully
transform itself on a nationalist basis. Communism in one country is an
impossibility.
Staying in or out of the Euro is not an option for the Greek working class since both options will involve austerity for it. Only communism precludes austerity. Syriza's anti-austerity platform is based on the false view that an austerity free membership of the capitalist Eurozone is possible for the Greek working class. Events are verifying the pro-austerity nature of Syriza. Even if Syriza was to take the working class out of the Euro austerity will still face it.
Consequently the entire debate as to whether Greece should stay within the Euro or not is a bourgeois debate of no real relevance to the working class. It is an option presenting itself within the limits of capital. Indeed present conditions concerning Greece are acutely manifesting capital's limits and the need to transcend them in the form of communism. Much of the Left, such as the Irish Socialist Party, show solidarity with Syriza in its pseudo anti-austerity campaign. In this way it is promoting capitalism and deceiving workers. Of course in Ireland the active politics of the Socialist Party suggest that anti-austerity is possible under Irish capitalism.
Staying in or out of the Euro is not an option for the Greek working class since both options will involve austerity for it. Only communism precludes austerity. Syriza's anti-austerity platform is based on the false view that an austerity free membership of the capitalist Eurozone is possible for the Greek working class. Events are verifying the pro-austerity nature of Syriza. Even if Syriza was to take the working class out of the Euro austerity will still face it.
Consequently the entire debate as to whether Greece should stay within the Euro or not is a bourgeois debate of no real relevance to the working class. It is an option presenting itself within the limits of capital. Indeed present conditions concerning Greece are acutely manifesting capital's limits and the need to transcend them in the form of communism. Much of the Left, such as the Irish Socialist Party, show solidarity with Syriza in its pseudo anti-austerity campaign. In this way it is promoting capitalism and deceiving workers. Of course in Ireland the active politics of the Socialist Party suggest that anti-austerity is possible under Irish capitalism.
Wednesday, October 2, 2013
The Reformism of Maurice Coakley
Below is a piece from me criticising the interview with
Maurice Coakely concerning his recently published book Ireland in the World Order: A History of Uneven
Development? The interview
was published on the website PoliticalEconomy.ie on March 28th 2013.
Maurice: It argued that the Irish capitalist class had been
shaped by this structural underdevelopment and showed no inclination to develop
an independent industrial base. From the 1960s onwards it sought to insert
Ireland into transnational networks – above all by making it a conduit for US
capital investment orientated towards the European market. Some of this was
manufacturing industry that created real employment but much of it was
fraudulent, with the Irish state becoming complicit with tax evasion on a
massive scale. While the country significantly increased its average standard
of living, it also made itself deeply dependent upon foreign capital.
Paddy: Maurice’s above use of the concept “underdevelopment”
is questionable. This is because in the course of his interview he suggests
that a sufficiently strong popular resistance movement can create conditions
within Ireland that liberate the Irish people from conditions of oppression. Since
such liberation from oppression, in its very nature, means an end to “underdevelopment”,
for Maurice then, the latter is not necessarily a socio-economic condition that
prevents independent development. For Maurice too the creation of these
conditions does not involve the abolition of capitalism. Given this his concept
of “underdevelopment” is of no historic significance.
Maurice: The radical left has long argued for greater
workers’ control at the level of manufacturing industry but we also need to
think through what needs to be done in other sectors of the social order. The
workings of government and its many institutions should be transparent to the
citizens and should be subject to democratic supervision. That would
necessarily involve participation and consultation not only with the workers in
any given institution, but also with citizens involved with them, like patients,
commuters, residents etc.
The minimum measures necessary to defend popular living
standards and the welfare state will face fierce opposition from the ruling
elites. If a pro-worker government is to succeed in these very modest goals, it
would need to achieve a deep popular mobilisation, and a politicisation of the
populace.
Paddy: The above indicates his conception is tantamount to
suggesting “structural underdevelopment” can be significantly modified or even dissolved
within the framework of imperialism. But the notion of “underdevelopment” is
based on the assumption that it is a necessary and unavoidable aspect of world
capitalism. Consequently “underdevelopment”
can only be eliminated by eliminating capitalism. This being so there is no
room for Maurice’s brand of reformism
within this theory.
To claim that this Irish capitalist class “showed
no inclination to develop an independent industrial base” suggests that
this indigenous class has had choice as to how the Irish economy was to be
structured. This then means that, for Maurice, “underdevelopment” is not an
inevitable outcome of world capitalist development but a product of the subjective
choices of the Irish capitalist class. This then suggests that the Irish
capitalist class is not dominated by imperialist
capital (British capitalism). But this must is evidence that Maurice is contradicting
the very nature of “underdevelopment”. This implies that the Irish bourgeoisie has
been a subjectively lazy or unenterprising class. Laziness, then, not “underdevelopment”
or foreign capital, is mistakenly the ultimate
source of the problem for Maurice.
The economic development of Western Europe in the aftermath
of the Second World War was largely determined by US capitalism. These Western
economies were in an extremely dependent state. Yet it would make little sense
to describe Britain, France and Germany as in a state of “underdevelopment” as
a consequence of its then subordinate relationship to US capitalism. Even today
there obtains a relationship of subordination between US imperialism and
Western Europe. Indeed Maurice’s claim that the capitalist world is composed of
a hierarchal state system suggests that there different degrees of structural
development with regard to individual states.
To historically link social resistance in Ireland to a
striving for national independence makes little sense. If Ireland’s condition
was that of “underdevelopment” then there obtained no possibility of national
independence been achieved. However the conditions existed for the realisation
of social rights or reforms within “underdevelopment”. Catholic Emancipation
was, in a sense, realised within the context of underdevelopment as was the
land question. Yet these movements of social resistance were not necessarily
linked “to a striving for national independence.” The conditions of nationality
entails the existence of an emerging indigenous bourgeoisie free from
conditions of “underdevelopment”. Given
Maurice’s perspective such an Irish bourgeoisie must be non-existent because of
underdevelopment.
The character of the Irish economy in relation to global
capitalism is not a result, as Maurice implies, of the subjective actions of
its capitalist class. The Irish capitalist class cannot subjectively determine
Ireland’s economic structure. If it could it would then constitute an
independent capitalist class involving an independent nation state.
Maurice resorts to petit bourgeois morality when he claims that
much of US investment has “a fraudulent nature”. It is no more fraudulent than the
exploitation of labour power. Collapsing economic and political phenomena into morality
merely obfuscates reality and obscures the way forward.
The Southern Irish state did not make itself dependent on foreign capital. The objective processes inherent
in world capitalism made it dependent on foreign capital. All capital is
ultimately dependent. Dependent on the industrial working class as the source
of value (capital). Neither foreign nor indigenous capital are morally better
than each other. One is as bad or good as the other. The point is that they are
both sources for the extraction of surplus value from the modern worker.
Maurice: At a more general level the book argues that uneven
development is intrinsic to the capitalist system. This is not just a matter of
the laws of the capitalism system working themselves out unevenly - though
there is an element of that - but also that patterns of development are heavily
shaped by politics. Global capitalism is a hierarchal system, and states play a
central role in moulding that hierarchy,
Paddy: Maurice’s claim that “global capitalism is a
hierarchal system” is a questionable and
rather undialectical claim. The USA was originally a British colony and then in
the 18th century was a relatively weak nation state. Yet it was to
eventually become the strongest capitalist state in the world. Germany was slow
to emerge into an independent state. Yet today Germany is, arguably, the strongest state
within the EMU. We see then that the strength and weakness of states is a
somewhat fluid matter.
Maurice: The failure to the Irish state to pursue a course of
independent economic development has made the Irish economy exceptionally
vulnerable in the event of crisis. The Irish state found itself with very
limited leverage to negotiate with the institutions of global and regional
governance.
Paddy: An individual state cannot freely choose to follow a
course of independent economic development. It is not a subjective matter. It is a
historical matter grounded in objective processes that transcend, albeit
involve, mere subjectivity. Otherwise any state could freely choose to follow a
course of independent economic development. If a country, such as Maurice
claims Ireland to be, is in a condition of underdevelopment then this is even
more so the case. States don’t have the power to subjectively determine the
character of their economies. Furthermore capitalism is international in
character which means that Irish capitalism is driven by global capitalism.
Maurice: To make matters worse the political elite has become
closely interwoven with a rentier/financial oligarchy whose interests are very
removed from any development project, or from the needs of the wider
population. The Irish elite as a whole has become characterised by a mentality
that combines dependency and fraud, a combination not uncommon across much of what
is called the ‘developing’ world.
Paddy: Capitalism, including Irish capitalism, is a class
based system –not an “elite” based
system. The Irish state is a capitalist state that ultimately serves the
interests of the capitalist class. Thereby this system never existed, as
Maurice suggests, to serve “the needs of the wider population”. The category “wider population included all
classes obtaining in a specific social formation. Neither can it be one of
“mentality”, as Maurice suggests.
Psychology is not the driving force of societies. A different “mentality” cannot
free Ireland from dependency and “fraud”.
Maurice: There has been a radical change in the balance of
forces between capital and labour – to the detriment of labour – over the last
few decades and this has been one of the defining features of contemporary
capitalism. Other significant changes have also occurred.
Over the last few decades, global capitalism – especially in
the North Atlantic economies – has been characterised by a massive expansion of
the financial sphere, a process known as financialisation. Behind the financial
upsurge are some wider changes in the global economy.
Paddy: The post-war world followed on the heels of the
massive defeat of the world working class at the hands of both capitalism and
Stalinism. Yet, in the aftermath of the war, the Western working class experienced, to a
large extent, radical improvements in both its working and living conditions. So
Maurice’s claim that changes in the balance of forces against the working class
necessarily involves falls in its living standards is not supportable by the evidence.
Maurice: One is the presence of global over-capacity in
production which inhibits investment. Too many goods are chasing too few
customers. Many corporations don’t see any way that they can achieve profitable
returns by investing in new production lines so they are either hoarding their
profits or looking for speculative fields to put their money in. In the old
core zones of global capitalism, investment rates have been falling for
decades.
Paddy: If the above comments are true then the recent industrial
development of China could not have
taken place on such an enormous scale. To suggest that profits are being
hoarded makes no sense. Hoarding profit (surplus value) can only mean the
contraction of profits. If surplus value, in the form, of profit is hoarded
then it ceases to function as capital. It thereby must contract. Even if industrial corporations invest their
profits in a bank they are still not being hoarded. Banks cannot make profits
by hoarding. Over-capacity in capitalist production cannot, given capitalism’s
nature, constitute a sustainable process. Over-production of capital occurs at a
particular stage in the business cycle. Over-production is followed by
stockpiling of commodity capital and the eventual devaluation and destruction
of capital itself. This entails the increased centralisation and concentration
of capital. The consequent capital adjustment brings about an end to this
over-accumulation of capital. But this cyclical process can be softened, even
interrupted, by progressively increasing public expenditure. The latter
ultimately constitutes a deduction from surplus value. But there is a limit to
this process. This is why the 2008 crash and the Euro crisis took place.
There cannot persist in a sustained way, as Maurice is claiming,
too many goods chasing too few customers. The goods, the commodities in
question, then cease to be goods (commodities). Too many goods chasing too few
customers is based on false underconsumptionist assumptions which conflict with
Marxist political economy.
Maurice: In this context financialisation was useful because
more people could buy goods on credit, but the huge debt which was built up
from the 1990s ultimately became unmanageable and the financial system
imploded. We are living with the consequences of that. Most of the world’s
banks are underwater, and have only survived because of massive infusions of
public money from governments around the world.
Paddy: Huge debts are a relative matter. The accumulation of
huge debts does not necessarily, as Maurice claims, become unmanageable leading
to the implosion of the financial system. The debt tolerance of capitalism is a
function of the scale of surplus value produced by its valorisation process. Debt
tends to cause problems when the valorisation process is producing insufficient
surplus value relative to debt.
Maurice: Because workers could not afford to buy the goods
produced, the credit system was vastly expanded to cope with this but it
ultimately collapsed under the weight of the huge levels of debt which had
accumulated. The crucial point is this: capital will not be able to resolve
the crisis this time by further assaults on labour. This does not of course
mean that they won’t try. But even if they are successful in their efforts, it
will not end the systemic crisis. On the contrary, it will deepen it because
ordinary people will be even less able to afford the goods being produced.
Paddy: Expanding credit excessively is capitalism’s means of seeking to escape from its profitability
problems. The enormous burgeoning of credit had a universal character in the
West. To claim that “assaults on labour” involving further cut-backs in the price of
labour power will not help resolve the crisis is ludicrous. To claim that such
a development leads to further underconsumptionism demonstrates Maurice’s
ignorance of the nature of capitalism. If there obtains a sustained accelerating
accumulation of capital then falling wages do not necessarily lead to falling
demand.
Maurice: Marx spoke about the ‘over-accumulation’ of capital.
We usually think about this as an economic process, but it is also a social
one. The huge wealth and power that capital has built up over the last three
decades has become an obstacle to the capitalist system itself
Paddy: But if, as Maurice claims, growth and profitability have
been falling then it cannot be the huge wealth and power of capital that is the
cause of the crisis. If profitability is
falling then the scale of capital is correspondingly contracting. To suggest,
as Maurice does, that capital would be rational if it followed a certain
programme is to misunderstand the nature of capital. The only way capital can
be rational is by its self-negation. The
very nature of these aspects make such rational action impossible under
capitalism.
Maurice: If capitalism was a rational system it would have
imposed harsh sanctions on the bankers and the brokers, and ensured that
sufficient resources went into social services and into the creation a
sustainable energy system. It would also make a serious effort to ensure that
the general population would be able to buy the goods being produced by
capital. But capitalism is not a rational system, or rather what is rational
for the individual capitalist – or the individual state – becomes irrational
for the system as a whole.
Paddy: Maurice is again engaging in contradictions. If, as
Maurice claims, capitalism is not rational then it is inconsistent of him to
call for a programme involving the public ownership of the credit system since
this would constitute a futile attempt to render capitalism more rational. Yet
he has already claimed that the capitalist system is not rational.
Maurice: If a substantial popular and democratic resistance
to neo-liberal polices does not emerge, we are likely to see a deepening of
destructive and irrational trends, alongside more imperialist adventures,
across the globe.
Paddy: Popular and democratic resistance is not the issue. The
issue is the emergence of a global communist movement that successfully overthrows
capitalism. Neither is it, as Maurice suggests, a matter of mere resistance to
neoliberalism but the mounting of a sustained offensive against the capitalist
class. Maurice’s antiliberalism suggests
that there is a good and a bad capitalism: defeating bad capitalism in the form
of neo-liberalism while restoring the previous good form of capitalism. The
only way to eliminate neoliberalism is to eliminate capitalism.
Maurice: To many people, including many trade unionists, this
seemed like a good deal. It is only with the global financial crisis that the
downside of the deal has become more evident. Suddenly, Ireland was being
demoted to the status of a ‘peripheral’ state, albeit a periphery of the
world’s second major core region. One of the reasons why resistance in Ireland
has been muted so far is because people are afraid that resistance could be
counterproductive, that deeper confrontations could damage Ireland’s position
in the global system. The EU leaders and the debt collectors are aware of these
fears and use them to their advantage.
Paddy: The problem is, not simply, as Maurice suggests, the
failure of the Irish working class to seriously challenge the cut backs. The
problem is that the cut-backs cannot be successfully challenged within a national
framework. Only the European working class, including the Irish working class,
can successfully challenge the cut backs by transforming itself into a working
class communist movement. On its own the Irish working class, no matter how
radicalised, is objectively too weak to
destroy capitalism in Ireland.
Maurice: While many are beginning to realise that there may
be a heavy price to pay for having so lightly abandoned national sovereignty,
they see no easy way to regain it.
Paddy: It is ironical that Maurice should suggest that
Ireland had (before the fall) national sovereignty given that he claims it has
been in a state of “underdevelopment”. Ireland’s has been surrendering its national
sovereignty over many years. To a
certain extent it has been the further loss of sovereignty, as a result of
becoming part of the Eurozone, that has led to the southern Irish economy’s current
disastrous economic condition. Indeed it
is questionable as to whether Ireland has
ever been an authentic sovereign country.
Maurice: The argument put forward by the European Commission
and the European Central Bank – that cutting public spending will rejuvenate
the private economy by making it more competitive – is simply not credible... It
is clear that the austerity programmes are not only having a disastrous social
effect, but are also damaging the capitalist economies in the affected
countries. Not only are these deprivation programmes socially and economically
harmful but they have also significantly eroded the position of the political
establishment in these states.
Paddy: Austerity does work. Indeed an austerity programme is
needed for Western capitalism as a whole. The reason as to why the Western capitalist class has not faced up
to its problems is because of fear of the working class. Divisions within that
capitalist class is another reason. If widespread austerity was introduced it
would lead to the demise of the weaker sections of the capitalist class. It is
this component of the capitalist class that may be more sceptical concerning an
austerity programme. For capitalism to recover there needs to be enormous cut
backs made in the living and working conditions of the working class together
with the elimination of less productive
forms of capital.
Maurice: To make matters worse, they are now forcing austerity
policies on their neighbours, ignoring the evidence that these are thoroughly
counter-productive. As an economic strategy, this was bound to crash because if
the peripheral economies are on their knees, who then is going to buy German
goods?
Paddy: Above is the false underconsumptionist rubbish
repeatedly spewed out by much of the radical left. If German capital is to
continue to accumulate it needs to export both commodities and capital to other
parts of the EU. To achieve this it needs to maintain and increase
profitability. Exporting capital is one of the chief means through which to
achieve this. This means keeping costs down including both the price of the
commodity labour power and social benefits. The imposition of EU wide austerity
can help prevent German profits from falling. This is done by reducing the
price of labour power and the elimination of weaker forms of capital. The
latter is largely sustained by state spending of one sort or another. The
biggest danger confronting the West European bourgeoisie, concerning this, is
the potential challenge from the European working class. However because
profitability conditions are so bad West European capital has no other option
but to take action that may lead to historically significant challenges by the
working class. However current working class weakness is encouraging it to impose
radical austerity.
Maurice: More than that, it would appear that as capitalism
becomes more mature, it can only be stabilised by more and more public
spending. Without that, these economies go into reverse gear. This is what is
happening today across the European periphery.
Paddy: The opposite is the case. Because of capitalism’s growing
maturity public spending needs reduction to a necessary minimum. It is enormous
public spending that largely constitutes a deduction from surplus value leaving
less room for the accumulation of capital.
Maurice: One way of overcoming Europe’s debt problems would
be to simply write off the debt. This happened to German debt in 1953, with the
blessings of Washington. Were the European Union to do this, it would be a
massive blow to the interests of financial capital, and it would probably force
the European states to take public ownership and control of the credit system.
Another solution would be to print money to inflate away the debt. This would
damage both the interests of financial capital and also of savers, who would
see the real value of their savings reduced. It is considered to be politically
unacceptable to the German government. Instead, the ECB, the EC and the Berlin
continued to push through austerity programmes that they know are
self-defeating. This whole policy is incoherent and behind the arrogance of the
European leadership one can detect more than a hint of panic.
Paddy: It is not the job of the working class to assist
capital in its effort to resolve its problems. Much of the Irish radical left
have been repeatedly engaged in this treacherous exercise. It is a reactionary
exercise which deceives the working class. The class interests of workers is
not advanced by announcing ways to save capitalism from itself.
Anyway the European Union won’t write off debts because this
means a reduction in total surplus value accruing to its capital –particularly
the capital of its strongest economies. It will only engage in such
undertakings when left with no alternative. The other solution promoted by
Maurice is “to print money to inflate away the debt.” Inflation is an
anti-working class measure involving consumer price rises which tend to reduce
working class income. Excessive money printing can destabilise capitalism.
Maurice: Some of the points that the Keynesians make are
valid enough. There is a necessity to increase public spending in both social
and physical infrastructure. We are, however, not likely to see a return to the
high growth rates of earlier decades, nor is it clear that high growth would be
a good thing. The Keynesians have yet to get their heads around the global
ecological crisis. Endless economic growth is simply not possible, nor is it
ecologically viable. The global environment is much too fragile for that. If we
are to establish a viable economic model, it has to include an agenda of moving
towards a sustainable energy system.
Paddy: Public spending means more debt. Excessive debt has
been a key source of the problem. Calling for a “pro-worker government” under
capitalism is tantamount to calling for more credit and public investment
independently of its profitability. Yet more credit, contrary to what Maurice
claims, only intensifies the problem.
Maurice: Given that a return to high growth rates is impractical,
it is difficult to see how a social compromise between capital and labour of
the sort that existed in the post-war decades could be revived. At a very
immediate level, the private banking system is a massive obstacle to economic
revival because it represents claims on future production. These claims are
strangling investment projects. This private financial sector needs to be
closed down, and the credit system should be turned into a public utility
system, like electricity, water or transport. A publically owned,
democratically structured credit system would enable the population to
determine where investment should go and what forms it would take. Such a
programme would not, in itself, abolish capitalism, but it would significantly
re-structure the system and shift the balance of power from capital to labour.
Paddy: The nationalisation of credit means more debt. Given
the global character of credit its nationalisation by a little Irish state is
impossible. In fact the public finance that is being injected into the world
banking system is a form of nationalisation by the back door. This enormous
financial cost is being undertaken at the expense of the working class. Bank nationalisation would prove an even
greater burden on the working class.
If the financial system was to be made public on a popular
democratic basis in such a way as to enhance the interests of the working class
the capitalist class would challenge this attempted restructuring of capital. The capitalist state then could not, by its
very nature, support such nationalisation. The nationalisation of finance is
just not possible under capitalism. Finance capital is by its very nature
private. Capitalism cannot be managed in the way that Maurice suggests, A
managed capitalism constitutes the
negation of finance capital.
Neither is capitalism going to shift what Maurice calls “the balance of power” against itself. The state is an organ of class power that cannot thereby serve the interests of the working class. Furthermore given the global character of finance capital a puny Irish state lacks the power to successfully challenge it. Neither capitalism nor its state are rational which means a rational capitalism cannot exist. Popularly determining where resources are to be invested means that profit is no longer to be capital’s driving force. This is to fly in the face of the law of value. This an historic impossibility.
Maurice: The crucial arena for establishing a modicum of self-determination is the financial one. The debt burden imposed upon the population is not only immoral, it is also impractical. It effectively condemns the state to extended stagnation, which will be accompanied by a gradual but accumulative reduction in social spending and social rights.
Paddy: The above piece makes no sense. Immorality is not the issue. Morality is not an economic policy. The category population includes capitalists, petty capitalists, the industrial working class and lumpen elements. In this context it is a term of great ambiguity even suggesting that Ireland is not a class society. Maurice’s conception suggests that the state is a neutral force that can be used by either working class or capitalist class.
Maurice: The details of what policies a progressive
government would need to introduce would have to be worked out collectively and
these would change over time depending on circumstances. In the 1930s trade
policies were considered more central than they would be now, but that could
change again. A lot of good work has been done by people like Michael Taft, the
Anglo Not Our Debt campaign, and the Irish Left Review.
Paddy: There can be no such political institution as a progressive Irish government. If such a government were possible then there is no reason as to why Fianna Fail, Fine Gael or the Labour Party would not have formed one. These parties don’t act in a reactionary way because they sadistically enjoy punishing the working class. The point is that they cannot function as government without being compelled to implement policies that serve the interests of the capitalist class both in its indigenous and foreign forms. Their policies are not a product of subjective factors but of objective ones. Furthermore the EU would obstruct the existence of a progressive Irish government.
Michael Taft is a reformist nationalist who sees the solution
as a reformist one that is confined within the Irish national framework. This
is a utopian solution.
Maurice: Any political advance towards a more just society
must begin from where we are now. In the case of western Europe, a defence of
social rights and the welfare state has to be the starting point for launching
a political challenge to the existing order, at least for the foreseeable
future.
Paddy: “A more just society!” Is this The Just Society
programme promoted by the Fine Gael Party in the second half of the 20th
century? It is not a matter of a defence of social rights and the welfare
state. Capitalism has launched an attack on the working and living conditions
of the Irish working class because it is left with no real choice. Why else
would it engage in such an exercise? Why is the state currently engaged in this
exercise on such a scale? The current government is not engaged in a severe
austerity programme because for the pleasure of it. It does not willingly
promote a programme that makes it increasingly unpopular. The point is that it
has no real choice under present circumstances.
Maurice: However, a strategy that is based solely of making
demands on the state and expects that the population, or the working class,
will become radicalised when these demands are not met, is hardly credible.
Politics has moved on over the last century and the ruling class now appeals
directly to the population – mainly through the media – arguing that while
certain social rights may be desirable, they cannot realistically be granted or
maintained because the state cannot afford them.
Paddy: Appealing to the population mainly through the media
is not to appeal directly to the population. The bourgeois mass media is a
reified form. It itself forms a part of the problem.
Maurice: If the left is to defend the earlier gains achieved
by workers and the wider population, it needs to explain how these social
rights are to be paid for. It is not good enough to say: “that’s their
problem”. It is our problem too.
Paddy: This above means that there is essentially no difference between “the left” and the two political parties currently in government. Both “the left” and the government are then arguing for policies within the narrow constraints of the national capitalist framework. The point is that the problems of the working class cannot be solved within the constraints of a national capitalist framework. Consequently the left cannot “explain how these social rights are to be paid for” under capitalism. This is because they cannot be paid for under capitalism. The bourgeois political parties are right when they make this claim. Again it has to be wondered what Maurice means by “the left”. Is this left to include the variety of different groups that are considered to be “the left”: ranging from Stalinism to Trotskyism. Is it possible for such a left to subscribe to the same programme (“socialism in one country”)?
Maurice: Re-distribution of income is only one part of a
programme of transition to a more equitable society. Another crucial aspect is
control over the credit system. This would involve not only having capital
controls but also a publically owned credit system.
Paddy: It is questionable as to how the above programme of
action can be successfully realised within the framework of the EU. The EU is
not going to passively sit by while this programme is implemented. A publicly
owned credit system used to benefit the working class is a contradiction. The
credit system forms a necessary part of finance capitalism. It exists to serve
the interests of capital as opposed to labour power. It exists to sustain and increase
the exploitation of labour power. Consequently it cannot be designed to benefit
the working class.
Maurice: The radical left has long argued for greater
workers’ control at the level of manufacturing industry but we also need to
think through what needs to be done in other sectors of the social order. The
workings of government and its many institutions should be transparent to the
citizens and should be subject to democratic supervision. That would
necessarily involve participation and consultation not only with the workers in
any given institution, but also with citizens involved with them, like
patients, commuters, residents etc. This kind of project would need to be
accompanied by the development of new democratic media.
Marx is often criticised for failing to outline a
comprehensive plan for a socialist society, but this is arguably a strength of
his position rather than a weakness. We have to begin from where we are and
work from there. The minimum measures necessary to defend popular living
standards and the welfare state will face fierce opposition from the ruling
elites. If a pro-worker government is to succeed in these very modest goals, it
would need to achieve a deep popular mobilisation, and a politicisation of the
populace.
Paddy: The above piece is grossly misleading.
However the problem is that many workers are deceived by such ramblings. There
cannot exist a “pro-worker government” under capitalism. To argue for a “pro-worker
government” is to paradoxically argue for a pro-worker (capitalist) state.
Should such a society be realisable there would be no need for communist
society.Sunday, January 22, 2012
An Outline Of A Model Of The Capitalist Industrial Cycle
The Capitalist Crisis
The capitalist economic system is a cyclical system of interrupted reproduction of wealth. It is this cyclical interruption that is known as the economic crisis or depression. Consequently invested constant and variable capital is significantly reduced. There thereby follows a significant decline in the scale of the reproduction of wealth and thereby the consumption of wealth by humanity. The result is increased poverty.
Capitalist crises tend to have an inherently cyclical character entailing the indefinite sequential expansion and contraction of the reproduction of capital. The capitalist economic cycle involves sequential phases that regularly repeat themselves. This is the necessary and contradictory form by which capitalism regulates itself indefinitely. It is a form of regulation that is inherently unstable tending to generate political crises, wars and even social revolution. Consequently the sustained existence of capitalism cannot be guaranteed.
Typical crises have a unique form peculiar to capitalist society. Under capitalism the material destruction of the elements of production occur not as the cause but as the result of the cyclical crisis. It is not because fewer workers are engaged in production that a crisis breaks out. Instead the opposite is the case: Fewer workers are engaged in production as a result of the break-out of a crisis. What appears to be the case is not the case. Reality is reversed. A capitalist crisis is a crisis of overproduction of exchange-values in the form of capital. On the market commodities fail to find buyers thereby rendering these commodities unsalable. Full employment is the exception rather than the rule under capitalism. At best full employment tends to have a cyclical character. Capitalist crises tend to have a generalised global character.
The intrinsic contradiction of the commodity, the contradiction between use-value and exchange-value, is externalised in the form of the splitting of the commodity into the commodity itself and money. The split creates the general possibility of capitalist crises. This contradiction means that to appropriate use-values one has to be able to buy them. To buy or sell one has to be a buyer or seller. Individuals exist, then, in the form of a buyer or a seller. They need only exist in this narrow abstract form. Power resides in one’s existence in the context of the constraining narrow abstract forms of buyer or seller. This circulation process plays a role in determining the character of the working class and the capitalist class. Consequently individuals are reified as the personifications of buying, selling and consumption. Consequently success is circumscribed by the constraints of the reified forms of buyer, seller and consumer. The worker as seller of labour power is only conceived from within that narrow form. This is why s/he is so summarily disregarded by the ruling class. His/her more humanist nature is thereby precluded, except marginally, from conceptions based on this socio-economic. One’s commercial value or status is significant not one's kindness, say, towards others. Consequently one is celebrated as a musician or artist because of one’s commercial success but not for one’s virtuosity and creativity. Since the worker’s existence is exclusively grounded in this constrained form, seller of labour power, his/her existence concerning every aspect of his/her being is conditioned by this narrow reified form. In past societies this was not necessarily the basis of economy. The separation between the commodity and its money equivalent facilitates the emergence of the systems of trade, credit and eventually capitalism. Accordingly these systems of reification conditioned the development of social being in such a way that they indelibly inscribe themselves on existing human conduct.
The Process of Circulation of Capital
The existence of circulation and thereby circulation time means that there is a time interval between sale and purchase or selling and buying. Circulation or the process of exchange rather than ensuring that every sale matches every purchase excludes any guarantee of the existence of such a condition. Circulation renders Say’s Law (supply creates its own demand) impossible. It prevents any guarantee that sales must match every purchase. In short there is an element of inevitable contingency featuring in the exchange process. It is this peculiar reification of human relations (circulation) that creates these conditions --the possibility of crises.
The circulation process is an inherently contradictory process. It is the necessary social form, albeit reified, by which commodities are distributed. It never guarantees that this distribution and realisation of exchange values will take place. There is thereby, as intimated, an element of contingency entailed in this process of reification. It is a contradiction that entails the existence of both necessity and contingency. This means the process of reproduction of both exchange value and thereby wealth can never be guaranteed under capitalism. This renders the general process of reproduction itself contingent. It is subject to chance even perhaps permeated by chance. Consequently the future can never be predicted with any certainty or accuracy. This being so capitalism can never be depended upon to reproduce wealth or to reproduce the present and thereby the future. This is why it must be dispensed with. The capitalist circulation process is both a combination of necessity and contingency. Without chance there can be no novelty, change nor development. However with chance there is the danger of the opposite occurring -loss.
Many agents active on behalf of the bourgeoisie in times of crisis are forever endeavouring to enhance or improve the circulation system. They hope to render the circulation process more rational and streamlined in such a way that as a mode of realisation and distribution it cannot hinder the flow of commodities and capital through the system. But this illusion entertained by these ideologues indicates their inability to comprehend the nature of capitalism and its circulation process in particular. They are under the illusion that it is the task to restructure the circulation process in such a way that Say’s Law can freely assert itself and thereby create economic freedom. Depending on their political allegiances some are of the view that circulation needs to be cleaned out by eliminating “the debris” (such as oversized banks and excessive regulation) fouling up the circulation sphere. For them the problem is the lack of authentically free markets. For them markets are over-regulated.
On the other side the circulation process or the market is too free. It needs much more regulation and interventionism to guarantee that it operates harmoniously serving the interests of the public.
But both sides effectively support the market, in one way or another, believing it to be a necessary social form of regulation. This means that both sides support capitalism. But today’s massive over-accumulation of debt is evidence that market relations (the circulation process), in whatever form, cannot form a central part of the solution. Neither can they see that the core problem lies much deeper --deep within the heart of the production process itself. The source of the problem is the contradiction that exists within the capitalist process of production itself. This process either has to be abolished (communism) or cyclically transformed under the freely operating industrial cycle.
Say’s Law
Vulgar economics argued that the total value of commodities is equal to the total incomes of the various classes of society. From this it is concluded that the total production of commodities is at the same time the production of the incomes needed to absorb these commodities. Hence arose the law of markets called Say's Law. This law excludes the possibility of general overproduction. At most it allows for the existence of partial overproduction, overproduction in some sectors alongside underproduction in others. This, it is claimed, is caused by the unbalanced distribution of the "factors of production" within the economy. The mistake of the law of the markets arises from neglect of the time-factor. It assumes a static system instead of a dynamic one. STOPPP
During intervals between sale and purchase the prices of commodities can vary, in either direction, thereby creating a surplus of incomes or a surplus of commodities without the corresponding change in the money form on the market. Furthermore the incomes distributed during a certain period of time will not necessarily be used to buy commodities during this period. Only the incomes of wage-earners tend to be immediately and entirely spent. Capitalists are under no obligation to invest all these exchange- values immediately thereby using them as purchasing power to acquire goods. With falling profitability many capitalists tend to postpone such expenditure. The hoarding of incomes, non-productive saving, may thus give rise to a surplus of income which corresponds to an overproduction of certain commodities. This, in turn, brings about an initial reduction in employment which may lead to overproduction spreading throughout other parts of the economy leading to a further decline in employment. In this way the vicious spiral progresses.
Disturbances may arise from the injection of money into the circulation process. Within the production process fixed capital is gradually written off over a number of years and then all at once replaced by the expenditure of the accumulated depreciation funds. In a smoothly working system, the annual fixed capital replacements are equal to the annual depreciation allowances. If the age-composition of existing machinery is unequal or if business conditions suggest a speeding up or postponement of renewals, orders for replacements will exceed depreciation allowances in some years and fall short of them in others years. This discontinuity in the expenditure of depreciation allowances for capital replacements disturbs the smooth course of the circulation process. This is responsible for fluctuations in employment and thereby profit. The accumulation of depreciation funds is a sale without a purchase, as is any saving, while any investment is a purchase without sale.
Indeed interruptions, delays in sale or purchase, are the necessary contradictory nature of the circulation process. This form is a necessary condition for the realisation of capital accumulation. Consequently circulation is both a form of motion and non-motion.
Say’s Law would only tend to hold under conditions resembling universal simple commodity production. However such an economic system is an impossibility. A society exclusively producing mere use-values, not values, cannot create overproduction. Increases in the organic composition of capital leading to a consequent downward tendency of the general rate of profit form the general laws of development of the capitalist mode of production. The capitalist mode of production thus acquires its characteristic rhythm of development. This rhythm proceeds in the form of cyclical alternate contractions and expansions.
During the crisis phase the commodity split into itself and money is stretched to the utmost leading inevitably to slump. The long-term tendency of the general rate of profit to fall does not assert itself in a linear form. Instead it asserts itself in a cyclical form. The stages of a classical cyclic model of capitalism are as follows:
Economic Recovery
Under conditions of the over-production of capital under-utilisation of existing production capacity leads to stock elimination. Consequently the demand for goods tends to exceed supply. Prices and profits eventually start to rise again. Some factories (probably under new ownership) which have been closed open again. Others operating below capacity eventually increase their operations to full capacity. This encourages capitalists to increase investments. This is because, when demand exceeds supply, less social labour is crystallised in commodities present than socially necessary. This implies that the total value of these goods easily finds its universal equivalent on the market. The factories operating at higher productivity levels, higher than the average, realise super-profits. Less productive enterprises, still surviving after the crisis, realise the average (normal) profit. The circulation time of commodities is reduced. Gaps between selling and buying grow increasingly shorter.
The orders for equipment from the consumer goods sector make possible recovery in several capital goods sectors. Recovery reduces unemployment and increases purchasing power which stimulates a new wave of investment.
Capital goods production is much less elastic than that of consumer goods. When recovery is well underway an interval appears between the order for additional constant capital and its delivery. During the interval there is a relatively big demand within Department Two for the commodities from Department One that are already available on the market. The prices of these goods will rise faster than the prices of consumer goods. This produces different rates of profit in the two sectors. The disproportion in the two sectors is shifted to prices and profit. Wages tend not to rise at the beginning of recovery owing to pressure from the industrial reserve army of the unemployed on the labour market. Factories not working to full capacity re-engage workers without any plant change. This tends to lead to a lowering of the organic composition of capital thereby increasing the rate of profit.
The expansion of production is slow at first. The demand for constant capital in the form of new plant and technology remains at a level lower that the supply which implies that the rate of interest remains very low. The coincidence of a low rate of interest with a rising rate of entrepreneurial profit leads to a general tendency by entrepreneurs to renew fixed capital. Investment in new plant cannot be generally undertaken incrementally. Assuming a constant rate of increase in output an individual firm cannot alter its fixed capital at a parallel constant rate.
Boom
Much of the available capital flows into production in order to take advantage of the increase in the average rate of profit. Investments rapidly increase. New enterprises are set up and old ones modernised. The newly launched enterprises raise the average level of productivity. So long as supply is exceeded by demand prices continue to rise and the average rate of profit remains high. The most modern enterprises realise substantial super-profits which stimulate fresh investment and develop credit, speculation etc.
The disequilibrium between rates of profit in the two sectors is now transformed into a disproportion between the rate of increase of their production. The capital goods sector experiences a burst of frenzied activity. It causes an increase in demand for consumer goods and even leads to shortages. Given that demand exceeds supply prices are higher so that the more productive firms earn super-profits. The rate of interest begins to rise. Eventually profit is maximised and aggregate effective demand is met. The cycle reaches its first critical point. One would expect falling demand to lead to a corresponding contraction in production. Such rationalism is impossible because of the inherent contradictory nature of capitalism. We see here how capitalism’s character obstructs the development of rationalism. In fact its anarchic nature promotes irrationalism. This helps explain why irrationalist ideology and religion is still prevalent.
A contraction of production leads to an increase in depreciation charges thereby raising costs. Capitalists try to overcome this problem by intensifying the use of the production apparatus and increasing the intensity of labour. An increase in the mass of surplus value is needed to offset the lowering of the general rate of profit. This implies increased productivity by means of technological progress.
Capitalists cannot know when equilibrium has been reached. Complications such as the publicly unaccountable existence of hidden inventories in the hands of speculators thwart access to such knowledge. Over and above all this, although not unrelated to it, markets don’t feel the effects of maximum productivity until months after that stage has been reached. Production therefore continues to increase. Due to credit expansion this goes on even longer. But ultimately there is a limit to credit expansion. Then banks stop lending money.
Put simply overproduction of capital and thereby commodities is not felt by the markets until months after that stage has been reached. Production persists even after the stage of overproduction has been reached. Credit relations accentuate this situation. Retailers and the firms in intermediate stages of production have to replenish stocks exhausted due to the depression. Sales increases encourage industrialists to undertake further production which may coincide with stagnation or even slight shrinkage of ultimate consumption. Even when final consumption has been reached factories continue to produce and retailers continue to stock up
Overproduction
As more and more commodities are hurled onto the market the relations between supply and demand change. Some of the commodities produced under the least favourable productivity conditions contain labour time which is wasted from the social standpoint. These commodities have become unsaleable at prevailing prices of production. Thanks to the expansion of the credit system these unproductive factories go on producing for a certain period. This is reflected in the accumulation of stocks, the lengthening of the circulation time of commodities and the widening of the gap between supply and demand. At a certain moment it becomes impossible to bridge the gap with credit. Prices and profits collapse. Many capitalists are ruined and the enterprises that work at too low a level of productivity are crowded out.
The disequilibrium between Department One, the capital goods sector, and Department Two, the consumer goods sector, first shows itself in the sphere of prices and the rate of profit thus spreads more and more into the spheres of production. The total amount of purchasing power for consumers' goods does not increase any further or at least very little. But production still continues to increase. Stocks first grow at the final stage (retail trade) then at the wholesale stage and finally in the industrial enterprises themselves. As this increase in stocks grows the entrepreneurs resist any immediate price falls which would mean a lowering in total stock value --a serious loss. Circulation credit is increasingly sought from banks. The banks themselves would have already extended substantially to enterprises in this sector. They put off as long as possible any credit refusal. This is because this would bring about the bankruptcy of these enterprises and so the entire loss of the capital already advanced in loan form. In the case of Ireland the fact that the banks were forced to stop lending to businesses meant that they lost much of the money capital lent to them. This increased the losses of the bank and thereby created the situation they sought to avoid. This leads to credit inflation leading to speculation and swindling. This tension on the money market and the finance market comes just before the reversal of the conjuncture and is marked by a sharp rise in interest rates.
Now obliged to put off their investment projects many enterprises use this capital to meet added circulation costs. (Some may even create hedge funds to conceal their debts so that their enterprises continue to appear to operate at profit ). The orders for capital goods thus increasingly fall. Production starts falling off in the consumer industry. The capital goods sector follows it in a vicious downward spiral.
The rhythm of production in the capital goods sector is governed by the expansion and contraction of production in the consumer goods sector. The capital sector uses borrowed money much more than the consumer sector. This is because of the higher rate of profit in this heavy industry sector. Rises in interest rates hits them harder. Emptying of their order books means falling consumer demand and rising stocks and falling profits due to rising wages and costs.
Demand for circulation credit accumulates. But the supply of money capital declines because the difference between the rate of profit and interest increasingly disappears. Enterprises short on money capital draw out their bank deposits and sell off their property, securities, shares and bonds. This brings about falls on the stock exchange and other financial markets. A snowball effect sets in. The massive burgeoning of derivatives, especially devices such as credit derivatives more than add to this problem. Banks refuse credit leading to increased bankruptcies debtors dragging down creditors. Soon an avalanche sets in. Investors are forced to sell stock at any price. This is the cyclical character of the capitalist economy.
Crisis
The fall in prices means that only the enterprises working under the most favourable conditions of productivity survive. Firms with super-profits now have to be satisfied with average rates of profit. A lower level of average profit is attained. This corresponds to the new organic composition of capital. The bankruptcy and closure of many factories means large-scale destruction of machinery and thereby fixed capital. The total capital of society is reduced through the devalorisation and destruction of capital. This smaller amount of capital is now more profitable than the previous amount of capital. Indeed it was the previous oversized capital that was the cause of the crisis.
The cyclical movement of capital is thus nothing but the mechanism through which the general rate of profit asserts itself. The latter regulates the reproduction of capital and thereby its development and decline. The tendency of the rate of profit to fall forces the adaptation of the amount of labour which is socially necessary, the individual value of commodities, to their socially determined value. Because capitalist production is not a consciously planned and organised process these adjustments take place a posteriori. For this reason the regulatory process necessitate violent shocks involving the destruction of enormous quantities of values and created wealth. Over and above all this it causes damage and destruction of thousands of lives.
The Depression
It takes time for stocks to be disposed of which means there is no change in unemployment. Many firms have had to use funds normally made use of for the renewal of fixed capital for other purposes. Consequently the activity of enterprises in the capital goods sector is much reduced. The consumer goods sector does not decline as much as the capital goods sector. Even the unemployed have to eat. Perishable goods cannot be put off to another time. Workers’ wages don’t fall as much as the fall in prices which helps keep up the sale of perishable goods. The demand for semi-durable goods does not collapse as much as those of durable consumer goods. Yet durable consumer goods sell more easily than capital goods. In the depression the disproportion between the two sectors will spread to the sphere of prices and profits.
The Return Of Economic Recovery
While the depression lasts industrial activity remains at an abnormally low level. However it never absolutely collapses. There is always some industrial activity. When the rate of profit is very low no reduction in the rate of interest will make any difference to a revival of investment. But the very logic of the stagnation creates the elements of recovery. The contradiction of capitalist stagnation contains the conditions of recovery, As stocks are disposed of thanks to the collapse in production the consumer sector is able to slightly increase its activity. The prices of these goods find a floor that tends to steady things. It is enough for these enterprises to remain stable for a certain period for these enterprises to start re-equipping. Everything encourages this. The price of raw materials and means of equipment are very low.
Funds at first hoarded make their way back to the banks. There is a reduction in the demand for money capital because of the absence of investment activity which is why interest rates are low. The low rate of profit which produces recession compels enterprises to introduce new methods of production. Costs of production falls make possible an increase in the profit rate. Investment thereby begins in the consumer goods sector.
But both sides effectively support the market, in one way or another, believing it to be a necessary social form of regulation. This means that both sides support capitalism. But today’s massive over-accumulation of debt is evidence that market relations (the circulation process), in whatever form, cannot form a central part of the solution. Neither can they see that the core problem lies much deeper --deep within the heart of the production process itself. The source of the problem is the contradiction that exists within the capitalist process of production itself. This process either has to be abolished (communism) or cyclically transformed under the freely operating industrial cycle.
Say’s Law
Vulgar economics argued that the total value of commodities is equal to the total incomes of the various classes of society. From this it is concluded that the total production of commodities is at the same time the production of the incomes needed to absorb these commodities. Hence arose the law of markets called Say's Law. This law excludes the possibility of general overproduction. At most it allows for the existence of partial overproduction, overproduction in some sectors alongside underproduction in others. This, it is claimed, is caused by the unbalanced distribution of the "factors of production" within the economy. The mistake of the law of the markets arises from neglect of the time-factor. It assumes a static system instead of a dynamic one. STOPPP
During intervals between sale and purchase the prices of commodities can vary, in either direction, thereby creating a surplus of incomes or a surplus of commodities without the corresponding change in the money form on the market. Furthermore the incomes distributed during a certain period of time will not necessarily be used to buy commodities during this period. Only the incomes of wage-earners tend to be immediately and entirely spent. Capitalists are under no obligation to invest all these exchange- values immediately thereby using them as purchasing power to acquire goods. With falling profitability many capitalists tend to postpone such expenditure. The hoarding of incomes, non-productive saving, may thus give rise to a surplus of income which corresponds to an overproduction of certain commodities. This, in turn, brings about an initial reduction in employment which may lead to overproduction spreading throughout other parts of the economy leading to a further decline in employment. In this way the vicious spiral progresses.
Disturbances may arise from the injection of money into the circulation process. Within the production process fixed capital is gradually written off over a number of years and then all at once replaced by the expenditure of the accumulated depreciation funds. In a smoothly working system, the annual fixed capital replacements are equal to the annual depreciation allowances. If the age-composition of existing machinery is unequal or if business conditions suggest a speeding up or postponement of renewals, orders for replacements will exceed depreciation allowances in some years and fall short of them in others years. This discontinuity in the expenditure of depreciation allowances for capital replacements disturbs the smooth course of the circulation process. This is responsible for fluctuations in employment and thereby profit. The accumulation of depreciation funds is a sale without a purchase, as is any saving, while any investment is a purchase without sale.
Indeed interruptions, delays in sale or purchase, are the necessary contradictory nature of the circulation process. This form is a necessary condition for the realisation of capital accumulation. Consequently circulation is both a form of motion and non-motion.
Say’s Law would only tend to hold under conditions resembling universal simple commodity production. However such an economic system is an impossibility. A society exclusively producing mere use-values, not values, cannot create overproduction. Increases in the organic composition of capital leading to a consequent downward tendency of the general rate of profit form the general laws of development of the capitalist mode of production. The capitalist mode of production thus acquires its characteristic rhythm of development. This rhythm proceeds in the form of cyclical alternate contractions and expansions.
During the crisis phase the commodity split into itself and money is stretched to the utmost leading inevitably to slump. The long-term tendency of the general rate of profit to fall does not assert itself in a linear form. Instead it asserts itself in a cyclical form. The stages of a classical cyclic model of capitalism are as follows:
Economic Recovery
Under conditions of the over-production of capital under-utilisation of existing production capacity leads to stock elimination. Consequently the demand for goods tends to exceed supply. Prices and profits eventually start to rise again. Some factories (probably under new ownership) which have been closed open again. Others operating below capacity eventually increase their operations to full capacity. This encourages capitalists to increase investments. This is because, when demand exceeds supply, less social labour is crystallised in commodities present than socially necessary. This implies that the total value of these goods easily finds its universal equivalent on the market. The factories operating at higher productivity levels, higher than the average, realise super-profits. Less productive enterprises, still surviving after the crisis, realise the average (normal) profit. The circulation time of commodities is reduced. Gaps between selling and buying grow increasingly shorter.
The orders for equipment from the consumer goods sector make possible recovery in several capital goods sectors. Recovery reduces unemployment and increases purchasing power which stimulates a new wave of investment.
Capital goods production is much less elastic than that of consumer goods. When recovery is well underway an interval appears between the order for additional constant capital and its delivery. During the interval there is a relatively big demand within Department Two for the commodities from Department One that are already available on the market. The prices of these goods will rise faster than the prices of consumer goods. This produces different rates of profit in the two sectors. The disproportion in the two sectors is shifted to prices and profit. Wages tend not to rise at the beginning of recovery owing to pressure from the industrial reserve army of the unemployed on the labour market. Factories not working to full capacity re-engage workers without any plant change. This tends to lead to a lowering of the organic composition of capital thereby increasing the rate of profit.
The expansion of production is slow at first. The demand for constant capital in the form of new plant and technology remains at a level lower that the supply which implies that the rate of interest remains very low. The coincidence of a low rate of interest with a rising rate of entrepreneurial profit leads to a general tendency by entrepreneurs to renew fixed capital. Investment in new plant cannot be generally undertaken incrementally. Assuming a constant rate of increase in output an individual firm cannot alter its fixed capital at a parallel constant rate.
Boom
Much of the available capital flows into production in order to take advantage of the increase in the average rate of profit. Investments rapidly increase. New enterprises are set up and old ones modernised. The newly launched enterprises raise the average level of productivity. So long as supply is exceeded by demand prices continue to rise and the average rate of profit remains high. The most modern enterprises realise substantial super-profits which stimulate fresh investment and develop credit, speculation etc.
The disequilibrium between rates of profit in the two sectors is now transformed into a disproportion between the rate of increase of their production. The capital goods sector experiences a burst of frenzied activity. It causes an increase in demand for consumer goods and even leads to shortages. Given that demand exceeds supply prices are higher so that the more productive firms earn super-profits. The rate of interest begins to rise. Eventually profit is maximised and aggregate effective demand is met. The cycle reaches its first critical point. One would expect falling demand to lead to a corresponding contraction in production. Such rationalism is impossible because of the inherent contradictory nature of capitalism. We see here how capitalism’s character obstructs the development of rationalism. In fact its anarchic nature promotes irrationalism. This helps explain why irrationalist ideology and religion is still prevalent.
A contraction of production leads to an increase in depreciation charges thereby raising costs. Capitalists try to overcome this problem by intensifying the use of the production apparatus and increasing the intensity of labour. An increase in the mass of surplus value is needed to offset the lowering of the general rate of profit. This implies increased productivity by means of technological progress.
Capitalists cannot know when equilibrium has been reached. Complications such as the publicly unaccountable existence of hidden inventories in the hands of speculators thwart access to such knowledge. Over and above all this, although not unrelated to it, markets don’t feel the effects of maximum productivity until months after that stage has been reached. Production therefore continues to increase. Due to credit expansion this goes on even longer. But ultimately there is a limit to credit expansion. Then banks stop lending money.
Put simply overproduction of capital and thereby commodities is not felt by the markets until months after that stage has been reached. Production persists even after the stage of overproduction has been reached. Credit relations accentuate this situation. Retailers and the firms in intermediate stages of production have to replenish stocks exhausted due to the depression. Sales increases encourage industrialists to undertake further production which may coincide with stagnation or even slight shrinkage of ultimate consumption. Even when final consumption has been reached factories continue to produce and retailers continue to stock up
Overproduction
As more and more commodities are hurled onto the market the relations between supply and demand change. Some of the commodities produced under the least favourable productivity conditions contain labour time which is wasted from the social standpoint. These commodities have become unsaleable at prevailing prices of production. Thanks to the expansion of the credit system these unproductive factories go on producing for a certain period. This is reflected in the accumulation of stocks, the lengthening of the circulation time of commodities and the widening of the gap between supply and demand. At a certain moment it becomes impossible to bridge the gap with credit. Prices and profits collapse. Many capitalists are ruined and the enterprises that work at too low a level of productivity are crowded out.
The disequilibrium between Department One, the capital goods sector, and Department Two, the consumer goods sector, first shows itself in the sphere of prices and the rate of profit thus spreads more and more into the spheres of production. The total amount of purchasing power for consumers' goods does not increase any further or at least very little. But production still continues to increase. Stocks first grow at the final stage (retail trade) then at the wholesale stage and finally in the industrial enterprises themselves. As this increase in stocks grows the entrepreneurs resist any immediate price falls which would mean a lowering in total stock value --a serious loss. Circulation credit is increasingly sought from banks. The banks themselves would have already extended substantially to enterprises in this sector. They put off as long as possible any credit refusal. This is because this would bring about the bankruptcy of these enterprises and so the entire loss of the capital already advanced in loan form. In the case of Ireland the fact that the banks were forced to stop lending to businesses meant that they lost much of the money capital lent to them. This increased the losses of the bank and thereby created the situation they sought to avoid. This leads to credit inflation leading to speculation and swindling. This tension on the money market and the finance market comes just before the reversal of the conjuncture and is marked by a sharp rise in interest rates.
Now obliged to put off their investment projects many enterprises use this capital to meet added circulation costs. (Some may even create hedge funds to conceal their debts so that their enterprises continue to appear to operate at profit ). The orders for capital goods thus increasingly fall. Production starts falling off in the consumer industry. The capital goods sector follows it in a vicious downward spiral.
The rhythm of production in the capital goods sector is governed by the expansion and contraction of production in the consumer goods sector. The capital sector uses borrowed money much more than the consumer sector. This is because of the higher rate of profit in this heavy industry sector. Rises in interest rates hits them harder. Emptying of their order books means falling consumer demand and rising stocks and falling profits due to rising wages and costs.
Demand for circulation credit accumulates. But the supply of money capital declines because the difference between the rate of profit and interest increasingly disappears. Enterprises short on money capital draw out their bank deposits and sell off their property, securities, shares and bonds. This brings about falls on the stock exchange and other financial markets. A snowball effect sets in. The massive burgeoning of derivatives, especially devices such as credit derivatives more than add to this problem. Banks refuse credit leading to increased bankruptcies debtors dragging down creditors. Soon an avalanche sets in. Investors are forced to sell stock at any price. This is the cyclical character of the capitalist economy.
Crisis
The fall in prices means that only the enterprises working under the most favourable conditions of productivity survive. Firms with super-profits now have to be satisfied with average rates of profit. A lower level of average profit is attained. This corresponds to the new organic composition of capital. The bankruptcy and closure of many factories means large-scale destruction of machinery and thereby fixed capital. The total capital of society is reduced through the devalorisation and destruction of capital. This smaller amount of capital is now more profitable than the previous amount of capital. Indeed it was the previous oversized capital that was the cause of the crisis.
The cyclical movement of capital is thus nothing but the mechanism through which the general rate of profit asserts itself. The latter regulates the reproduction of capital and thereby its development and decline. The tendency of the rate of profit to fall forces the adaptation of the amount of labour which is socially necessary, the individual value of commodities, to their socially determined value. Because capitalist production is not a consciously planned and organised process these adjustments take place a posteriori. For this reason the regulatory process necessitate violent shocks involving the destruction of enormous quantities of values and created wealth. Over and above all this it causes damage and destruction of thousands of lives.
The Depression
It takes time for stocks to be disposed of which means there is no change in unemployment. Many firms have had to use funds normally made use of for the renewal of fixed capital for other purposes. Consequently the activity of enterprises in the capital goods sector is much reduced. The consumer goods sector does not decline as much as the capital goods sector. Even the unemployed have to eat. Perishable goods cannot be put off to another time. Workers’ wages don’t fall as much as the fall in prices which helps keep up the sale of perishable goods. The demand for semi-durable goods does not collapse as much as those of durable consumer goods. Yet durable consumer goods sell more easily than capital goods. In the depression the disproportion between the two sectors will spread to the sphere of prices and profits.
The Return Of Economic Recovery
While the depression lasts industrial activity remains at an abnormally low level. However it never absolutely collapses. There is always some industrial activity. When the rate of profit is very low no reduction in the rate of interest will make any difference to a revival of investment. But the very logic of the stagnation creates the elements of recovery. The contradiction of capitalist stagnation contains the conditions of recovery, As stocks are disposed of thanks to the collapse in production the consumer sector is able to slightly increase its activity. The prices of these goods find a floor that tends to steady things. It is enough for these enterprises to remain stable for a certain period for these enterprises to start re-equipping. Everything encourages this. The price of raw materials and means of equipment are very low.
Funds at first hoarded make their way back to the banks. There is a reduction in the demand for money capital because of the absence of investment activity which is why interest rates are low. The low rate of profit which produces recession compels enterprises to introduce new methods of production. Costs of production falls make possible an increase in the profit rate. Investment thereby begins in the consumer goods sector.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)